|
|
THE REAL WELFARE SCANDAL
by Walter Lippmann and Cliff Conner
-------------------------------------------------------------------------------------
This
article first appeared in the International
Socialist Review, May 1973,
pp.
16-23. It was later included in the anthology Life in Capitalist
America: Private Profit and Social Decay (Pathfinder Press, 1975),
pp.103-120, from which this was scanned in 2012. The George Tooker image
appeared in black-and-white in the ISR version of the article.
This version was taken from the Internet.
George Tooker: Government Bureau (1956)
What
is welfare? Webster's Unabridged defines the
word
as meaning: “The state of faring or doing well; thriving or successful
progress in life; a state characterized
especially by good fortune, happiness, wellbeing, or prosperity. . . .”
In the United States in 1973 some 16 million people are on “welfare,”
but for them
Webster's
definition can only hold the bitterest sort
of irony.
These 16 million welfare
recipients—nearly 8 percent of the American population—live
in poverty. Their existence will be characterized by dilapidated
housing, unsanitary and unsafe living
conditions, hunger, dreariness,
disease, and degradation. Virtually none will enjoy even a minimal level of the basic necessities for
a decent life—in the midst of the
richest society in world
history. This is the real American “welfare scandal.”
Adding insult to injury, almost all federal, state, and
local politicians are attempting to
make these victims out to be
villains. In the loud debate over the need
for "welfare reform," the constant
implication (frequently made explicit) is that people on welfare are
typically lazy, shiftless, and dishonest. In addition, there are
attempts to play on the deep-rooted
racism of whites by oblique hints that their rising taxes are
caused by Blacks and Latinos who refuse to work.
By this logic, the "welfare bums"—who are stealing the wealth of the
country and getting a free ride at everyone else's expense—are a root
cause of the United States' obvious social and economic predicament.
This is the viewpoint that tends to dominate the mass media's treatment
of the welfare problem.
To divert the public's attention from the real problem of poverty in
America and its causes, the "welfare mess" has been made a political
football. A leading ballhandler has been Richard Nixon, who publicly
hailed a popular song ("Welfare Cadillac") that portrays welfare
recipients getting rich and living lives of leisure at public expense.
At the same time, his administration has attempted to camouflage
measures designed to increase the oppressiveness of the welfare system
as a "welfare reform" program. The axis of political debate on this
question can be gauged by the fact that Nixon's "reform" proposals were
blocked by congressional right-wingers and were supported by some of the
liberals.
In reality, the system of welfare payments in the U.S. amounts to doling
out benefits with the proverbial eye-dropper, keeping millions of
Americans at the barest subsistence level and preventing them from
breaking out of their impoverished condition. The genuine social problem
that the rapidly increasing welfare rolls indicate is the growing
incapacity of the American economy to provide enough jobs.
Who are the welfare recipients?
The welfare rolls are indeed growing by leaps and bounds. In the ten
years since 1963, the number of Americans on welfare has more than
doubled. In January 1969, at the beginning of "Work Ethic" Nixon's first
term, the number was still under 10 million, but in 1972 it passed the
15 million mark.
Who are these welfare recipients? A breakdown of the statistics clearly
refutes the widespread notion that they are able, but unwilling, to work
for a living. There are four federally-subsidized welfare programs: Aid
to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC), Old Age Assistance (OAA),
Aid to the Blind (AB), and Aid to the Permanently and Totally Disabled (APTD).
Also, some local areas provide general relief or assistance funds.
According to the U.S. Department of Health, Education and Welfare, there
were nearly 15 million people drawing benefits from one or more of these
programs in January 1972. Of these, 10.7
million were
parents and children on AFDC, 2
million were aged, 1.1 million
were blind or otherwise disabled, and 1
million were on locally-funded relief
or assistance programs.
The biggest category, accounting for
72 percent of the total, is
AFDC recipients. These 10.7 million people
were almost all either children or
mothers of dependent children.[Footnote
1]
Only in a very limited number of cases is
a
family with two "able-bodied" parents allowed to draw
welfare payments, no matter how destitute they may
be.
Therefore, the overwhelming majority of those on
welfare are clearly: 1) too old to work, 2) too young
to
work, 3) unable to work because of lack of child
care
for young children, 4) blind, or 5) disabled. These
figures expose the demagogy of "workfare" schemes and
Nixon's contraposition of "the work ethic" to "the welfare
ethic."
But
these statistics conceal another important aspect
of the
welfare system; that is, that the welfare rolls
are a
manifestation of disguised unemployment. Many
recipients are mothers who are unable to work due
to
the lack of day-care facilities for their children. And
many
of those recipients who are physically unable
to
work are dependent on welfare because their former
means
of support joined the ranks of the unemployed.
Disguised unemployment
The
sociologist Herbert Gans, writing in the March 7,
1971,
New York Times Magazine, put his finger on the real cause of the
poverty that forces millions onto
welfare: "When an economy cannot provide work for everyone, some people
have to be excluded from the
work
force." The capitalist system of production for
private profit cannot exist
without some degree of unemployment
built into the system itself.
In Capital, written
over a century ago, Karl Marx
explained this in terms of capitalism's need for a "reserve army of the
unemployed," which serves to hold
wages of employed workers to a minimum
and provides a ready pool of
labor to be tapped when the business cycle enters a period of economic expansion.
Marx, describing this "surplus
laboring population," wrote:
"It forms a dispensable industrial reserve army,
that belongs to capital quite as absolutely as if the latter
had bred it at its own cost. . . . it
creates, for the changing
needs of the self-expansion of capital, a mass of human material
always ready for exploitation."
This is an unavoidable result
of the drive to maximize profits in an anarchistic, unplanned
system of production for an unknown market. That some degree of unemployment
is inevitable in their economies is tacitly
acknowledged by capitalist governments when they
define "full employment" as some
"tolerable" level of
unemployment. In the United States, for example, government
bureaucrats (who are not only employed but highly paid) have indicated
that 4 percent unemployment is,
to them, tolerable. Since the American labor force now stands at
83 million workers, 4 percent unemployed equals 3.3 million people.
But the actual level of official unemployment is now
over 5 percent, accounting for well
over 4 million workers, and
the government has given no indication that it considers this higher
level intolerable, either. The millions of unemployed workers
themselves, of course, are not likely
to share the government's cavalier appraisal of their deprivation of
livelihood as "tolerable" and
"acceptable."
Furthermore, it is widely recognized
that the official U.S. unemployment statistics fall far short of revealing
the full extent of joblessness in America. The more
than 4 million officially unemployed only include those
who are registered at state
employment centers as seeking
work. Many millions more have concluded that
pursuing nonexistent jobs is futile
and have dropped out of the statistics altogether. These
discouraged job hunters account for
much of the widespread poverty that finds its reflection in the
burgeoning welfare rolls. That explains the fact that the numbers of
welfare recipients continued to climb
rapidly even in the mid-sixties,
when by the capitalists' standards, their economy
had reached a "full employment"
level.
While some level of unemployment has always been
characteristic of capitalism, the problem has become
qualitatively more critical in the
United States since World War II. Here it is necessary to distinguish
between two kinds of unemployment: conjunctural and
structural. Conjunctural
unemployment is directly related
to the ups and downs of the business cycle. Structural unemployment, on the contrary, results from the
introduction of more productive
machinery so that more goods
can be produced with fewer workers. This latter kind of
unemployment, marked by a permanent loss of
jobs regardless of the market, has
continued to rise in the
United States.
There are several reasons for the
changing employment pattern in American industry. Increasing
foreign competition has led American
monopoly capitalism to mount a
productivity drive, resulting in the introduction
of "labor saving" machinery at an accelerating rate. Combined with
speedup and rationalization of
the labor process this has meant that
the creation of new jobs has
not kept pace with population growth
and the elimination of old jobs. In
particular the advances in technique, especially automation and
cybernation, have contributed to
major increases in structural unemployment.
While the American economy has
continued to employ a steadily
growing number of workers, the proportion
of the labor force unable to find jobs has also increased. In the past,
the reserve army of the unemployed
was generally put to work during boom periods. However, during
the height of the mid-1960s boom
unemployment remained in the millions.
The continued rise of
structural unemployment is the
fundamental factor underlying the rapid increase in welfare
dependency. This type of unemployment has
hit Blacks the hardest. Blacks are the
last to be hired and the first
to be fired. The displacement of sharecroppers in the South by corporate farms during and after World War II
sent millions of poor Black farmers to the cities looking for
jobs. Despite the postwar economic
upswing, the urban labor markets failed to absorb
many of them. These people and their descendants
make up a substantial proportion of the welfare population.
The changing social composition of Newark, New
Jersey, illustrates this process. The Black proportion
of the city's population increased
from 34 percent to 54 percent
between 1960 and 1970, and today over 25 percent of Newark's inhabitants
are on welfare. While the Black
population in the U.S. is 10-15 percent
of the total, 43 percent of the country's welfare
recipients are Black.[Footnote
2]
When
it becomes clear that American capitalism
creates widespread poverty by spawning unemployment,
it becomes equally clear
that welfare victims can in no way be
held individually responsible for their own impoverishment.
Far from bearing the blame for America's social ills, they are
among the most severely oppressed by
the present system of social organization.
And the millions on welfare are not
the only poverty-stricken
Americans. Herbert Gans, in the article cited
earlier, estimated that some 30 to 50 percent more
people are eligible for welfare today
than are in fact on the rolls. Welfare rules and regulations are
designed to discourage and prevent as many people as possible
from applying for and receiving any form of relief.
Welfare: What's in it for the capitalists?
Therefore it is not surprising
that, even by the government's
conservative estimates, in addition to welfare
recipients another 11 million Americans were living
in poverty in 1970.
In their frequent rantings
about the "welfare mess,"
Democratic and Republican politicians leave the distinct
impression that they think most welfare programs
are unjustified and should be
scrapped. Is there any chance
that they might decide to do away with the
welfare system altogether and leave the present recipients
to their own devices for survival? This is highly improbable.
A report issued by the New York
City Department of Social
Services gives a partial indication of
the effect such a cutoff would
produce in that city:
"A seventh of the city's population would be without food. There
would be no rent payments for those people
on welfare. Several hundred thousand
would have to be placed in institutions at a cost 6 to 8 times greater
than that required to keep them with
their families. There would be
a great likelihood that the number of
deaths among the elderly would go
up."
[Footnote
3]
Commenting on this report, the New
York Post pointed to "the
tremendous social consequences which
could arise if welfare, or another
sort of relief program, were not an integral part of the American system.
'People just won't sit home quietly and starve
to death,' said one official."
The welfare system serves an
absolutely essential function
in a modern capitalist economy. The state
dole to the poor acts as an
anticyclical device that
tends to minimize the threat of economic and social convulsions.
Welfare not only sustains the reserve army of the
unemployed that the capitalists draw
upon during periods of
expansion; the huge government expenditures
also serve to moderate the upswings and downswings of the
business cycle. Above all else, the capitalists hope to avoid the turbulent "boom-and-bust" cycles
that led their system to the brink
of doom in the 1930s. Welfare
payments distribute purchasing power—money for rents,
utility bills, groceries, etc.—to millions of
people deprived of any other means of
earning it. If they were cut off, the economic shock waves would
be felt far beyond the ranks of the recipients themselves.
The food stamp program, for example,
since it restricts purchases to foods grown in the U.S., acts as
a subsidy for American agribusiness.
[Footnote
4]
The
ultimate danger that the capitalists want to avoid
is
the social explosion that could result from a deep economic
crisis. That explains their willingness to make
welfare payments in order to absorb
social tensions and to curb extreme swings of the economic pendulum. In
fact, in most advanced capitalist
countries welfare, unemployment insurance, and Social Security
payments are the primary anticyclical
device in the governmental
budgets. In the United States they are second only to
the Pentagon's expenditures.
Another function of welfare
payments in the American
economy is to subsidize marginal businesses. An
underemployed worker—a borderline
case between the employed and
unemployed—is low-paid and may be forced to rely directly or indirectly
on welfare checks for survival. L.V. Jones, a seasonally employed
farm worker, testified in Cairo,
Illinois, before the U.S. Commission
on Civil Rights that he receives welfare benefits during the winter, but
is cut off completely every May: "Sometimes I don't make $20 a
month, but they don't care. They don't
ask you is that enough or
nothing. When work is opened up I am supposed to go to work
regardless whether I can get a job or not."
Reverend Cobb of the Cairo NAACP,
testifying before the same
commission, revealed that these workers were being forced to
accept jobs paying fifty cents per hour!
Also, some local governments
are now attempting to reduce their payrolls by replacing civil
service workers with welfare
recipients. The New York City Parks Department,
for example, has eliminated nearly four
hundred jobs in this way since 1970,
paying welfare clients $2.65
per hour instead of the $5.43 civil service wage for the same
work.
How much welfare does welfare provide?
In 1970, the Office of
Economic Opportunity reckoned that the poverty line for a single
person would be $153 per month. In reality, of course, this figure is
very conservative, but it is useful as a basis of comparison
with welfare payments.
The central core of the welfare
system is the Aid to Families
with Dependent Children program. In 1971,
the national average monthly
allowance per person given by
AFDC grants was $48.70. These grants varied
widely from state to state and from
region to region: from $12.05 in Mississippi, $9.00 in Puerto
Rico, and $15.20 in Alabama, to $70.95
in New York, $69.15 in
Massachusetts, and $70.40 in Alaska. Thus New
York State, with the largest average
monthly per-person payments in
the nation, grants less than half of the
$153 that OEO designates as the upper limit of poverty.
Most AFDC programs are based on the assumption that a definite
amount of income is necessary to allow
each welfare family to subsist—a
specified "need standard." The states then purposely give the families less
than this amount. This is what the
welfare ideologists call a
"work incentive." If welfare clients do succeed
in getting part-time or substandard jobs, a certain
percentage of their welfare allotment is taken out for
each dollar they earn. They are
usually allowed to earn
slightly above the "need standard"—still below the
accepted poverty lines—before welfare
is cut off entirely. But what about those who cannot work? For the great
majority on welfare the so-called work incentive
is merely an excuse to reduce their payments to an
even lower level of bare subsistence
than the penurious "need
standards" established by the welfare offices.
Timothy Sampson, in
Welfare: A Handbook for
Friend and Foe, gives a
dramatic comparison of welfare
allocations and official poverty standards. He
shows that the average AFDC family of
four with no outside income
(which represents about 60 percent of the total) lives on $2,364
per year. Those with additional income
average $2,784 per year. By comparison,
the 1971 Social Security
Administration's estimated poverty line for a family of four was $4,137, and the Bureau
of Labor Statistics "Lower Budget" (considered
the minimum for a decent standard of
living) was $7,214 for a
four-person family. Since welfare grants
have by no means kept pace with inflation, those on
welfare today are in worse shape than
they were when these
comparisons were made.
The welfare bureaucracy, ever vigilant, has crammed
the system full of checks and
balances to keep the recipients from rising above absolute
destitution. In the AFDC program
there is a proportional cutback in welfare
payments for earned income above the "need standard,"
with the absolute cutoff usually at one-third over
the "need standard." For the aged and
disabled, however, there is a
dollar for dollar reduction in welfare
for every periodic raise in Social
Security benefits.
Welfare mothers, marching on picket
lines against welfare agencies all over the country, have
sometimes carried signs saying:
"Thanks for nothing." While better-off
citizens may mutter "ingrates" under their breath, the
welfare mothers are more than
justified in their contempt
for their "benefactors."
In addition to impoverishment, the welfare system
generally dishes out a large helping
of degradation to the
recipients. While rank-and-file welfare workers
all over the country have at times
tended to ally themselves with their clients, the welfare
bureaucracy has stepped up its
efforts to ensure that nobody beats the system out of an extra
nickel or dime. Welfare workers are
required to play the role of cops in enforcing the
restrictive regulations.
In the first place, in order to qualify, the clients are
confronted with mountains of
confusing paperwork and other
red tape. Much worse are the customary invasions
of privacy. Midnight raids by welfare
investigators, for example, checking up to see if an "abandoned" welfare mother
is having a sex life, still occur, although
such blatantly outrageous practices have declined as
clients have begun defending their
rights.
Until a recent court decision,
welfare benefits in Los Angeles
were routinely denied if the client refused to
identify, give the whereabouts of, or
sign a complaint against an absent parent. After the court decision struck down
this degrading rule, the Los Angeles County
Department of Public Social Services
informed its caseworkers that "No applicant/recipient can be denied because
of (1) refusal to be interviewed by the District
Attorney, or (2) refusal to give the identity or whereabouts
of an absent father. . . ."[Footnote
5]
However, in the next
paragraph, entitled "Policy," the caseworkers were told:
"It is NOT required that an applicant or recipient be
told that she has no obligations to
answer questions or to be
interviewed by the District Attorney concerning
these matters and, in accordance
with state instructions, she
should NOT be so advised."
(Emphasis and double emphasis
in original.) A government agency specifically
instructs its employees not
to tell the welfare clients what
their rights are! While it is certainly rare to find such
a straightforward example of welfare
hypocrisy in the form of a
printed, official directive, this typifies the
actual relationship of the welfare
system to those it purports to be helping.
Welfare "reform"
A fundamental tenet of the American
welfare system is that no recipient should be allowed to draw
benefits that even approach the wage
level of the lowest-paid
workers. An early formulation of this conception was
contained in a report of the English
Poor Law Commission in 1834,
which stated:
"The first and most essential
of all conditions . . . is
that [the welfare recipient's] situation on the whole
shall not be made really or apparently so eligible [i.e.,
desirable] as the situation of the
laborer of the lowest class. .
. . Every penney bestowed, that tends to render
the condition of the pauper more
eligible than that of the independent laborer, is a bounty on
indolence and vice."
It was only in 1898 that
the first state public welfare
plan, for aid to the blind, was instituted in the U.S. In 1912, Illinois
adopted the first statewide program
of family aid. The federal
government took no responsibility
for welfare programs until the time of the Great Depression of
the 1930s.
In 1935, under the public
assistance titles of the Social
Security Act, the federal government
agreed to pay a percentage of
state welfare allotments under a cost-sharing formula. This
system persists today.
In August 1969, Richard Nixon
went on national television to
announce a new welfare reform scheme,
which he dubbed the Family Assistance
Plan (FAP). Although it was formally discarded early in 1973, the
FAP was the focus of public debate
over welfare for almost four
years. It called for establishing a "national
income floor" for a four-person family
at $2,400 per year, a little
more than half of the CEO's poverty line.
It also incorporated the concept of
"workfare" by stipulating that
every welfare family member designated "employable" would have to
accept work or job training of any
kind offered by the government under threat of termination of benefits.
"Employable" was to include
anyone not physically ill, under sixteen years of age,
or responsible for children under age
six (this was to have been reduced to age three in 1973!).
But in spite of the FAP's
total insensitivity to the
real needs of people on welfare, congressional conservatives still
thought it overly generous. In 1971 the Senate
Finance Committee rewrote the plan and
Tom Wicker, a New York Times columnist who was sympathetic to
the original FAP, described the
revised version as "a
horrendous concoction called a 'guaranteed employment
program' that virtually abolished
welfare as such and would force family heads to work at substandard wages,
in either public or private jobs, at
$48 a week for those who could
not find them elsewhere. This is a cheap-labor
scheme to provide a big pool of workers who
would be forced to accept less than the minimum wage, with
starvation their alternative."[Footnote
6]
While
this particular bill was never passed, the general
description could apply almost as well to the Talmadge
Amendments to the 1972 Social Security Act, which were
passed
by Congress without a word of discussion and
put
into effect on July 1, 1972. Under the Talmadge
provisions, every mother with a child over age six
must
register for work or training at employment offices
(sometimes referred to as "human resources development"
offices). She has the choice of either accepting
whatever job or training program is handed out or
losing her welfare payments.
In essence, this legislation put the forced-work provisions of the FAP into federal
law without setting even the meager
$2,400 floor under incomes. (Talmadge
and other southern senators led
the opposition to a nationwide
guaranteed income figure, because equalizing welfare payments in every state
would have required substantial
increases to southern
recipients, thereby undermining the low-wage structure enjoyed by
industry in that part of the country.)
Putting "workfare"
legislation into the lawbooks and
implementing it, however, are two
different matters. In most instances welfare officials have proceeded with
caution, experimenting with small
numbers of recipients in "pilot programs" with the hope of gradually
extending them to cover the whole welfare population.
Even so, the welfare clients have not
remained passive in face of
these measures designed to further exploit
them and drive them off welfare
without providing decent jobs. Thus far the states have not carried out
any large-scale forced-labor
schemes.
Even the pretense of reform,
which was never really supposed to ease the lot of the impoverished
recipients in the first place,
was dropped on January 29, 1973,
when Nixon announced his budget for
the 1974 fiscal year. While increasing the allocation to the Pentagon
by $4.7 billion, to a whopping
$81.1 billion total, Nixon's
proposed budget called for sharp cutbacks of some
seventy domestic programs in the
fields of education, social services, welfare, child care, and others.
The president's budgetary
trimming was not greeted by
public indifference; on February 20, in a demonstration
called only a few days earlier, 10,000 people
marched in protest in Washington, D.C. Dozens of similar
protests, led by the National Welfare Rights Organization
and other groups, took place all across the country in early
April.
The reductions in federal support to child-care programs
are expected to force many working women
from productive employment onto
welfare. The Los
Angeles Times, for
example, estimates that some 40
percent of the children presently in
day-care programs in that
city will be turned out. For that reason, feminist
and welfare rights organizations have
responded by demonstrating behind the slogan: "Child care, not welfare!"
The entire national debate over
welfare, as carried out in the
halls of Congress and in the mass media, has
been based on false premises. The
conservatives' "workfare" and "work incentive" concepts ignore
the fact that the poor cannot create
their own jobs. The liberals' plaintive cry for "more jobs" is not as
repugnant, but is equally
useless in that it assumes the American economy,
as presently structured, to be capable of providing
an "adequate level" of employment. And those liberals
who call for "more money" to the poor are far
too timid in their perspectives. When
militant welfare clients led
by the National Welfare Rights Organization
broke into the debate with a demand for a $6,500 guaranteed
yearly income, the liberals became nervous.
The New York Times expressed
this queasiness editorially:
"The 'welfare rights' lobby
has needlessly and unhelpfully complicated liberal efforts to
reach an understanding with the
administration by its insistent demands
for a guaranteed income of $6,500 a
year and by its strident
attacks on the Administration plan.
"There is no chance of
attaining that utopian figure. [Could the arrogant editorialist
live in utopia on $6,500 a year? The
argument in Congress has always ranged
between $2,400 and $3,000 a year for a
family of four."
[Footnote
7]
What are the solutions?
If the
great national welfare debate is so obviously
founded on fallacies, why do the Democratic and Republican
politicians generate such heat over it? What
function does the continuation of
this inane discussion serve
for them?
As previously noted, it
provides a diversion from the
genuine social problems. More specifically, by promoting
the idea that welfare clients are loafing chiselers
living at the expense of working
people, it aims to divide the
very forces that could actually solve the
problem—the employed and unemployed
sections of the working
class.
Welfare recipients do not
constitute a special caste
that is unique unto itself. They are not a group of people
who are congenitally incapable of making valuable
contributions to society. People
on welfare are a subsidiary
category of the unemployed—part
of the working
class that, through no fault of its
own, is excluded from the
ranks of productive workers.
The social problem manifested
by the present welfare system
can only be successfully tackled by united action
on the part of employed and unemployed
workers. Such unity could take the form of the organization of
the unemployed into the trade union
movement. Another form of unity
could be alliances of organized welfare
clients and organized workers.
Whatever the organizational forms, the key to such joint action is a program
of demands that can unite the two
groups for a fight in their
common interests.
Such a set of demands would have to include a crash
program to provide adequate jobs for
those who can work, and full
union-scale wages for unemployed workers.
The latter demand, if won,
would eliminate the poverty of
the unemployed and protect the economic
security of employed workers. But this
is obviously not a demand
that can be presented to individual employers
on a one-at-a-time basis by local unions; it would have to be
presented to the capitalists' government
in Washington and would need the united strength
of the entire working class behind
it. If the government pleads poverty, the workers need only point to
the more than $81 billion that the
Pentagon has budgeted for imperialist war and demand that it be
put to constructive use instead.
Such an occurrence would certainly be anathema to
the capitalist rulers. Is it any
wonder that they go to such
lengths to portray those on welfare as social parasites
sucking the blood of the working class? If the New
York Times
indignantly rejects the $6,500 annual income demand as utopian, can
you imagine their reaction to a call
for full union-scale wages for the unemployed?
The objection many workers might raise
to such a proposal comes from
the politician/media barrage concerning "work incentives": "If
everyone were guaranteed a decent
standard of living, nobody would bother to work." This, again, echoes
the lie that welfare recipients
are responsible for their own plight, when it is
actually American capitalism that is to blame. The victims
of the system should not be required to pay for
its shortcomings by being forced to
live in poverty. A guaranteed
decent standard of living for the entire
working class is precisely the minimum goal to be fought for.
The central programmatic demand
around which employed and
unemployed can unite in struggle is the
demand for a reduction in the workweek
with no loss in pay. If there
are not enough jobs to go around
for the whole American working class, then the jobs
that do exist should be shared.
Instead of three thousand people working at a given factory for forty
hours per week, why not employ four thousand workers for
thirty hours per week? This more
equitable distribution of jobs should be effected at the capitalists' expense;
the three thousand original workers
should not be forced to take a
cut in pay to provide jobs for the other one
thousand. After all, it is not the
workers' fault that their
employers' drive for maximum profits excludes millions of people
from employment.
If the community of
interest between those on welfare
and organized labor has not always
been readily apparent, it is
rapidly becoming more so. According to
the April 3, 1973, issue of the Wall Street Journal, “The Nixon administration's line is hardening on the
politically explosive issue of paying
welfare benefits to strikers."
Nixon's aim, of course, is to limit the ability
of workers to strike. This is an important challenge
to the labor movement, and the AFL-CIO
has announced its intention to
support the right of striking workers to at least the minimal economic
security of welfare payments.
Unfortunately, the ossified
AFL-CIO hierarchy, tied to the capitalist political parties, cannot be
counted upon to lead an
effective fight in defense of this right. The much more
fundamental struggle for changes that
can eliminate poverty and unemployment and remove the need for the
rotten welfare system altogether will
require an entirely new leadership
for the organized working
class. George Meany and the whole bureaucratic
stratum he represents will have to be replaced
by militants capable of leading an
uncompromising struggle in the interests of all workers, including the unemployed.
While the labor movement
has the decisive power to bring
about the necessary changes—ultimately a socialist society—it
will have many allies, and some of
them are already in motion. Welfare recipients themselves
have organized and fought for their
rights during the past few years on a scale not seen since the unemployed
movement of the 1930s, and they have
been successful in striking
down many of the barriers used to deny
relief money to applicants. The
feminist movement has organized actions in defense of working and welfare
women, particularly around the issue
of child care.
The Black and Chicano
liberation movements, demanding
control of social institutions in their communities,
and the student movement, representing an
important segment of the American proletariat of the
near future, also have a large stake
in eliminating the inequities
of the present welfare system and can
be counted on to play a significant
role. With adequate leadership
and program there can be no doubt that these social forces will
be able to resolve the "welfare problem."
NOTES
1. In 1971, only 323,000 (3
percent) of the 10.2 million
AFDC recipients were adult males. Of these, 197,000 were incapacitated and unable to work. These HEW figures were cited
by Congressman Ben Blackburn in the
April 9, 1973, Congressional Record, p. H2497.
2. Another 48 percent are white; the remainder are Asians,
Native Americans, and others. The statistics fail to indicate
whether Chicanos and Latinos are classified as "whites" or "others."
3. Quoted in the New York
Post, March 29, 1971.
4. Except for coffee, tea,
and bananas.
5. Los Angeles County
Department of Public Social Services,
Manual Letter Number 154, dated March
19, 1973.
6. New York Times,
May 21, 1972.
7. New York Times, August 1, 1972.
WALTER LIPPMANN is a member of the California State Executive Board
of Social Services Union, Local 535 and was recently a Socialist Workers
Party candidate for School Board in Los Angeles.
CLIFF CONNER is an associate editor of the ISR.
|
|
|